The Pennsylvania State
University
Department of Economics
Fall 2009
Economics 434
Professor Barry W. Ickes
International Finance
and Open Economy Macroeconomics
Office: 618
Kern Graduate Bldg.
Course: Tuesday
and Thursday, 4:15 to 5:30, 121 Sparks
Office Hours: Monday
10-11, Thursday 10-11
Course Website: http://econ.la.psu.edu/~bickes/434home.htm
Introduction
This is a one-semester course in international
finance and open economy macroeconomics.
In this course we study how monetary economies interact. International
finance is the macroeconomic counterpart to international trade. The latter
studies the determination and impact of flows of goods and services across
national economies. In international finance we study trade in financial assets
and national monies across national economies and their impact. These are
fields that are linked together but there is an important difference in focus.
In trade theory the primary focus is the welfare consequences of international
transactions. In international finance the primary focus is on the stability of
the international monetary system. Of course we are now in the midst of the Great
Panic, a worldwide financial crisis. We will try to understand some of the
origins of this crisis, especially those that emanated from world imbalances.
And we will examine what reforms are necessary to make it harder for such
crises to spread in the future.
Why this class may be
important is suggested by some reports that the dollar is losing its status as
the world’s reserve currency:
China’s central bank renewed its call for a new global
currency in June and said the International Monetary Fund should manage more of members’ foreign-exchange
reserves. Russian President Dmitry Medvedev
last month illustrated his call for a supranational currency by producing a
sample coin after a summit of the Group of Eight nations.[1]
Why might the dollar
lose its status? Why does it matter to us? These are questions we will try to
answer. Sometimes this material gets downright exciting:
A
former Thai central bank governor has been fined 186bn baht ($4.6bn; £2.5bn)
for his leading role in the country's 1997 financial crash. Rerngchai
Marakanond spent that figure trying - and failing - to prop up the country's
currency during the crisis. The Bangkok Civil Court has now ordered that Mr Marakanond
must reimburse the Bank of Thailand within a month. Otherwise he will face the
seizure of his personal assets. The case was brought by the Thai government.[2]
There is a lot of action
in this subject. Recall the words of Miss Prism:[3]
Cecily,
you will read your Political Economy in my absence. The chapter on the Fall of
the Rupee you may omit. It is somewhat too sensational. Even these metallic
problems have their melodramatic side.”
I will try to limit the
melodrama, but events in this area are often sensational. Some interesting policy issues will frame our
discussion. One of the most important for the US is the size and sustainability
of the current account deficit. The US borrows nearly $800 billion from the
rest of the world each year, almost
7% of US GDP. What are the implications for the US and the rest of the world of
such large current account deficits? If the deficits are not cut what will
happen to the dollar? If they are cut what will happen to the world economy?
Another set of important issues are related to
currency crises. Many of the recent
currency crises – Argentina, Brazil, Russia and Turkey come to mind – have
occurred in emerging market economies. These sometimes lead to contagion –
recall the “Asian Flu” of 1997-98 and the threats to the international monetary
system. The Argentine crisis of 2001 led to dramatic political and social
turmoil. Why do economies, especially emerging market economies, suffer so much
from such crises? The causes and consequences of these crises, and what can be
done to prevent them, is an important issue. It is especially important to
understand whether these crises are in fact contagious.
The discussion of currency crises and what to do about
them merges with the issue of “globalization,” that is now in the air. Many now
question the recent moves to liberalize capital markets (and open markets in
general). The argument in favor of capital market liberalization is that it
improves the allocation of resources, and thus enhances global income. In the
past, international flows of capital have helped economies industrialize. But
there seems to be a side effect from such flows: currency and debt crises. This
leads some to debate the wisdom and timing of such liberalizations. This debate
is important so we shall discuss it. It also leads into a discussion of
international financial architecture and reform of the international monetary
system.
We will also examine the relative merits of
alternative exchange rate regimes. Should countries fix their exchange rates,
or should they allow them to float? Currently the US would like China to
revalue its currency, the yuan, or at least to end its fixed value with
respect to the dollar (in the hope that the yuan would appreciate). Is this a
good idea? Should the nominal value of currencies be determined by market
forces, or should they be fixed by central bankers? Your gut reaction may be
that all prices should be determined by market forces so flexible exchange rates
are necessarily superior (a view apparently shared by former Treasury Secretary
John Snow). Understanding the error in this analogy is only a first step to
analyzing the more appropriate exchange rate policies. We will want to examine
which types of exchange rate regimes are most popular? If market-determined
rates are so good, why has Europe moved to a common currency? What about
currency boards? Are they a panacea for international financial problems? These
are some of the questions we will look at.
In order to answer these
and other questions we will need to develop a basic understanding of
international macroeconomics. The determination of exchange rates, the
fundamentals of capital flows, and the macroeconomics of an open economy are
critical elements. We will need to develop these fundamentals in order to make
sense of the grand policy issues.
Course Issues and
Philosophy
It is useful to make
clear at the start some issues of teaching philosophy. As you will learn, I
find this material very interesting. My goal is to make you find it
interesting. I enjoy the material and am very enthusiastic about it. I will try
hard to convey why this is interesting and important. There are costs to this
approach, however. This is not material that has been taught so many times that
it practically runs by itself. There is no autopilot in this course. This means
that you will have to work. You
won’t do well if you are not prepared to work hard and think. In the past my
attitude has always been the following: “I am not a monitor. I will not enforce
you to supply effort.” I had always thought students have enough incentive to
do homework problems on their own. Student evaluations (and test performance)
seem to indicate otherwise. So this year we will have (at least four) homework
assignments. These assignments will count for up to 10% of your final grade.
Economics is a
quantitative subject. It is about stuff that we count. So we will use lots of
numbers. It is also an analytic subject: economists have a hard time
understanding arguments that do not involve models. Models make the subject
matter easier, not harder, but they enforce discipline on thought. So we will
make use of some elementary algebra. This is not really above high school
levels, but sometimes the sight of mathematical symbols causes psychological
paranoia. So be warned. You can see examples of what we do in some of the
lecture notes online.
This course is clearly
not just theory (but there is a lot of that) and the connection with real world
events will be evident. This means that the material is dynamic. Events will
upset the order of the topics. A lot of material on current events will get
added to the website.[4]
And, as new developments occur I will restructure the plan (I will update this
syllabus on the web whenever necessary, keep checking). The syllabus is only a
rough guide to what we will do each week. If you desire lots of structure you
are in the wrong course. I
cannot emphasize this enough.
Past exams are available
on the website along with answer keys. This semester the exams will look a bit
different due to the size of the class. Nonetheless, past exams provide a
plentiful supply of problems to practice and learn from. You should use this
free resource.[5]
Attendance in this
course accounts for 5%. This is a somewhat small (though not insignificant)
direct contribution to your grade. The indirect contribution, however, is much
larger. One reason is that the lectures do not repeat what is in the book. They
are complements, not substitutes (what point would there be to the lectures,
otherwise). Past experience suggests that students who do not attend class
typically fail exams and drop out.[6]
Perhaps you can be the exception. In any event, there will be a seating chart,
and I will record attendance.
While attendance is a
choice that is left to you, tardiness
is not. Showing up late to class not only demonstrates a lack of respect
to the instructor, it is also shows a lack of respect to other students. It is disruptive
to lectures. It is a negative externality that is dumped on your fellow
students. It is not fair to other students to show up late. Better not to show
up at all than to show up late (unless you have a good excuse). Of course, it
is best to show up on time. You are all too civilized to dump your garbage on
your neighbor’s lawn or car. Extend this courtesy to fellow students.
Administration
The textbook for this
course is Feenstra and Taylor, International
Economics. Worth Publishing, 2008. In the outline below the book is listed
as FT. In addition I have lecture notes posted on the website. I tend to follow
my lecture notes, but the book provides plenty of additional material and is a
very productive way to learn the material.
All administrative
announcements will be made on the course website. Please check the website
frequently for various items of information. I will update it as frequently as
I can.
Whenever possible I will
put readings on the web site for this course. There are more readings there
than you can probably digest in a whole year. Much of the readings are for
further interest. I will also put materials that are discussed in class there
whenever possible. Before exams I will also put review questions on the
website.
There will be two
midterm exams in this course, plus the final exam. The first midterm will count
for 20% of the total points, the second midterm will count for 25%, and the
final will account for 35%. Recall that homework accounts for 10% of the grade.
Of course, this is the direct effect of homework. There is an indirect effect
as well. If you do well on homework you should also do well on exams, so the
return to doing well on homeworks (as opposed to obtaining the correct answer
via copying) should be much higher than 10%. The remaining 5% will be based on
attendance.
The midterms will take
place in class. The first midterm will be on Tuesday, September 29, 2009. The date of the second midterm will be Tuesday, November 3.
Class Outline
The list of topics will
resemble the following outline. This is a plan not a blueprint. It will
probably change from time to time. I will put amended versions on the website
from time to time. Please take note of this warning. If you need a week-by-week
detailed plan of readings this is not
the course for you. Some students do not like the flexibility that I retain in
this course structure.[7]
If you like more organization you really should switch to a different course.
Note that for the most
part I only list here lecture notes (in the version of this syllabus on the
website the underlined portions are hyperlinks) and chapters in the FT book. In
addition, however, there are plenty of readings on the website that relate to
the material of given lectures. I put it there for your benefit. I hope you
take advantage of it.
I. Introduction
FT, chapter 12
II. The Theory of International Capital
Flows and Globalization
Lecture Note on Current Account in an
Intertemporal Framework
FT, chapter 17
III. The Great Panic and the International
Financial Crisis
Lecture Note on the Financial Crisis
IV. International Financial Markets
Lecture Note on International Financial Markets
Lecture Note on the Real Exchange Rate
FT, chapter 13, 22
[First Midterm about
Here]
IV. The International Monetary System in
Historical Perspective
Lecture Note on the Gold Standard
FT, chapter
19, section four
V. The Asset Approach to the Exchange
Rate
Lecture Note on Exchange Rate Fluctuations and Overshootinghttp://econ.la.psu.edu/~bickes/forex.pdf
FT, chapter 14-15.
VI. Income Determination in the Open Economy
Lecture Note on Income Determination
Lecture Note on Real Depreciation
FT, chapter 18
[Second Midterm about
Here]
VII. Currency, Debt, and Financial Crises
Lecture Note on Currency Crises
Lecture Note on Argentina
FT, chapter 20
VIII. Fixed versus Flexible Exchange Rate,
Monetary Unions, and New Bretton Woods
Lecture Note on Optimum
Currency Areas
FT, chapter 19, 21
IX. The International Monetary System and
Reform of Financial Architecture
FT,
chapter
Disability Access
Statement
The Pennsylvania State
University encourages qualified people with disabilities to participate in its
programs and activities and is committed to the policy that all people shall
have equal access to programs, facilities, and admissions without regard to
personal characteristics not related to ability, performance, or qualifications
as determined by University policy or by state or federal authorities. If you
anticipate needing any type of accommodation in this course or have questions
about physical access let me know as soon as possible.
Penn State
defines academic integrity as the pursuit of scholarly activity in an open,
honest and responsible manner. All students should act with personal integrity,
respect for other students’ dignity, rights and property, and help create and
maintain an environment in which all can succeed through the fruits of their
efforts (Faculty Senate Policy 49-20).
Dishonesty of any kind
will not be tolerated in this course. Dishonesty includes, but is not limited
to, cheating, plagiarizing, fabricating information or citations, facilitating
acts of academic dishonesty by others, having unauthorized possession of
examinations, submitting work of another person or work previously used without
informing the instructor, or tampering with the academic work of other
students. Students who are found to be dishonest will receive academic
sanctions and will be reported to the University’s Judicial Affairs.
Department Statement on
Valid Excuses
During the course many possible situations may arise that would result in your
inability to attend class, attend exams, or perform at a minimally acceptable
level during an examination. Illness or
injury, family emergencies, certain University-approved curricular and
extra-curricular activities, and religious holidays can be legitimate reasons
to miss class or to be excused from a scheduled examination.
In the case of your own illness or injury, confirmation from a
physician, physician’s assistant, a nurse-practitioner, or a nurse is
required. Be advised that University
Health Services cannot provide such verification unless they have provided
treatment and the student authorizes release of information to the instructor. Further, barring extraordinary circumstances,
the confirmation must be available to the instructor prior to the missed course
event.
With regard to family
emergencies, you must provide verifiable documentation of the emergency. Given the vast array of family emergencies
the instructor will provide precise guidance as to what constitutes adequate
documentation. Unless the emergency is
critical you should notify the instructor in advance of your absence from the
scheduled course event. In cases of
critical emergencies, you must notify the instructor within one week of your
absence.
For University-approved
curricular and extra-curricular activities, verifiable documentation is also
required. The student should obtain from
the unit or department sponsoring the activity a letter (or class absence form)
indicating the anticipated absence(s).
The letter must be presented to the instructor
at least one week prior to the first absence.
In the case of religious
holidays, the student should notify the instructor by the third week of the
course of any potential conflicts.
With regard to family
emergencies, you must provide verifiable documentation of the emergency. Given the vast array of family emergencies
the instructor will provide precise guidance as to what constitutes adequate documentation. Unless the emergency is critical you should
notify the instructor in advance of your absence from the scheduled course
event. In cases of critical emergencies,
you must notify the instructor within one week of your absence.
For University-approved
curricular and extra-curricular activities, verifiable documentation is also
required. The student should obtain from
the unit or department sponsoring the activity a letter (or class absence form)
indicating the anticipated absence(s).
The letter must be presented to the instructor at least one week prior
to the first absence.
In the case of religious
holidays, the student should notify the instructor by the third week of the
course of any potential conflicts.
Please see me if you have concerns or comments about
the course. If you would like to provide feedback about this course you
may also contact the Director of Undergraduate Studies in Economics or leave a
comment in the box that the Department maintains in 303 Kern.
[1] http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601083&sid=aCM5WaqsP.98.
[2] BBC, May 31, 2005.
[3] Oscar Wilde, The Importance of Being Earnest, 1895.
[4] I have also created a blog, http://ickmansblog.blogspot.com/ where I will make posts on items of interest. Hopefully you will find some interesting enough to comment on.
[5] People often ask whether the final will be cumulative. This is a question that one should never ask. Why? The essential meaning of this question is “can I forget everything you taught before the last exam?” It is bound to be insulting to any instructor to hear such a question. Everything we do in the early part of the course builds a foundation for the latter part of the course. How can the discipline be anything but cumulative?
[6] This does not really explain why I give points for attendance. After all, aren’t the costs of absenteeism internalized (i.e., via a low grade)? The problem is not that students who fail to attend lectures do poorly on exams (they do, but that is their problem, not mine). It is that students who fail to attend lectures and then do poorly on exams then pose an extra burden (on me) later in the course (pleading for extra credit, trying to learn in 3 weeks what they should have learned over 12 weeks, etc.). This makes paternalism a potentially optimal social policy.
[7] Some students will ask me from time to time where we are on the syllabus. I am always perplexed by this question. If you listen to the lecture you know the subject. The reading list is divided by subject headings. Hence, you ought to be able to look at the outline and see what you should be reading. What could be more obvious?